Wednesday, May 29, 2013

Cervical cancer is one of Mexico’s most lethal ones, killing 8 out of every 100,000 women every year.  When GlaxoSmithKline and Merck Sharp & Dohme developed vaccines against the human papillomavirus, the leading cause of cancer of the cervix, Mexico was among the first countries to consider a program of universal vaccination for twelve-year-old girls.
 
It appeared to be very cost-effective.  At some 440 pesos a dose, about the price quoted by Glaxo, offering a three-dose course to 80 percent of girls would cost just over 42,000 pesos per each healthy year of life that would be saved by the procedure, according to a 2008 analysis by researchers at the Mexican national health department.  This is less than half Mexico’s gross national product per capita, and thus considered a good investment by experts at the World Health Organization.
 
But because Mexico is a relatively poor country, these finding produced a conundrum.  A universal vaccination plan would cost about 1.4 billion pesos, almost as much as the entire budget for the government’s series of  seven mandatory childhood vaccines.  So the government took a Solomonic approach.  It decided to offer the vaccination program only in poor areas of the country with a relatively high incidence of cervical cancer, which would cut the total outlay by more than half.  More controversially, rather than provide the three doses within a period of six to eight months, as suggested by the pharmaceutical companies, the health ministry chose to provide the third dose only after five years.
 
“All our studies of the vaccines’ effectiveness were based on a plan of three doses – the third must be taken eight months after the first,” said Miguel Cashat-Cruz, the head of vaccines for Merck’s Mexican subsidiary.  But Eduardo Lazcano-Ponce, a researcher at the National Institute of Public Health, said pecuniary interests drove pharmaceutical companies’ protests.  “They say it won’t be useful, but they make no effort to reduce the price of the vaccine.”

The provision of health is awash in such cost-benefit calculations, as governments allocate limited budgets among new drugs and therapies streaming out of the world’s labs.  In 2005 New Zealand’s Ministry of Health declined to fund a universal vaccination program against pneumococcal disease that would cost about 120,000 New Zealand dollars for each year of life gained in good health by the inoculation.  It approved funding two years later, when the manufacturer proved that a program could be carried out for 25,000 New Zealand dollars per year of life.
The British government, which since World War II has provided health coverage for it’s citizens free of charge, has been the trailblazer in systematically applying cost-benefit analysis to its expenditures on health.  It started in the last 1990s, when the erectile dysfunction drug Viagra appeared on the market and officials at the National Health Services worried that the new wonder drug would bust the government’s health budget. 
 
These days, the National Institute for Health and Clinical Excellence – or NICE – follows a standard set of guidelines to determine which drugs and procedures will be covered.  Anything that costs less than £20,000 per year of good-quality life is approved.  And except in very rare cases, the health service will not pay more than £30,000 per year of added life.  The practice has spread around the world.  The Canadian Agency for Drugs and Technologies in Health makes recommendation to the nation’s provincial drug plan on the cost-effectiveness of new drugs.  From Australia to the Netherlands to Portugal, economic evaluations are mandatory for the approval of treatments.
 
The World Health Organization has developed general threshold for countries around the world.  It deems treatments very cost-effective when each year gained in good health cost less that the nation’s economic product per person, cost-effective when such a quality-adjusted life year costs one to three years GDP per capita, and not worth the investment when it costs more than that.  This metric would suggest that governments in countries like Argentina, Brazil, or Mexico should afford treatments if they cost less than $29,300 per QALY in 2009.  Their poorer neighbors,  like Bolivia and Ecuador, should only afford interventions costing up to #13,800.  The rich countries in the hemisphere, the United States and Canada, should be willing to invest up to $120,000 per year of good life gained.
 
Yet decisions based on cost-benefit calculations are never easy.  In 2008 it seemed straightforward for NICE to reject paying for Sutent, Pfizer’s newfangled pill for kidney cancer that cost about £3,189 for a six-week regimen and usually extended life by less than a year.  This meant it generally cost more than the agency’s £30,000 limit per “quality adjusted” year of additional life.
 
But the storm of public protest that ensued was deafening.  A British tabloid, the Daily Mail, called it a “death sentence” for those suffering kidney cancer.  And NICE backtracked, approving Sutent for some patients on the grounds that “although it might be at the upper end of any plausible valuation of such benefits, in this case there was a significant step-change in treating a disease for which there is only one current standard first-line treatment option.”  The investment, in fact, would not be too large.  Fewer than seven thousand Britons suffered this kidney cancer and Sutent would be suitable for only about half of those.  Moreover, Pfizer also offered to pick up the tab for the first six weeks.
 
It’s hard to overcome the belief that we are entitled to all the health care we need.  During President Obama’s push to reform American health insurance, the White House reminded its allies never to use the dreaded word “rationing.”  Democrat Max Baucus, who as chair of the Senate Finance Committee was one of the leading legislators crafting the bill, said: “There is no rationing of health care at all” in the proposed reform.
 
Of course, rationing is pervasive across the American healthcare system.  For starters, in 2009, 46 million American lacked health insurance.  A study of victims of severe traffic accidents who landed in hospital emergency rooms in Wisconsin found that those without health insurance received 20 percent less care than the insured.  They were kept only 6.4 days in hospital, on average, compared to 9.2 days for those with insurance.  And hospitals spent on average $3,300 more on the insured than the uninsured.  The uninsured, of course, were 40 percent more likely to die.  The study found that if hospitals treated the uninsured equally to the insured, each life saved would have cost $220,00, which amounts to about $11,000 per additional year.  This is a bargain compared to Sutent; well within the limits imposed by Britain’s NICE.
 
Nonetheless, Obama’s political tactics made sense in the face of accusations from American conservatives that the government wanted to take over the decision of who lived and who died.  The president got a foretaste of the oppositions tactics when a White House proposal to study the relative effectiveness of new drugs and therapies, to decide which were most worthwhile, drew a furious reaction.  An editorial in the Washington Times compared the proposal to a program called Aktion T-4 put in place in Nazi Germany to euthanize elderly people with incurable diseases, critically disabled children, and other unproductive types.
 
The rhetoric was effective because it tapped into the belief that life is priceless, and when it comes to matters of life and death we should spare no expense.  As Joy Hardy, the wife of a British cancer victim who was temporarily denied Sutent by the NHS said: “Everybody should be allowed to have as much life as they can.”  The belief has burned the United States with a uniquely inefficient healthcare syste.  In 2009 health care consumed 18 percent of the nation’s income.  And without any mechanism to ensure cost-effectiveness, it could swallow more than a fifth of the economy by 2020.  Yet all this spending does not buy better health.
 
Somehow Americans have a lower life expectancy at birth than the Japanese, French, Spanish, Swiss, Australians, Icelanders, Swedes, Italians, Canadians, Finns, Norwegians, Austrians, Belgians, Germans, Greeks, Koreans, Dutch, Portugese, New Zealanders, Luxembourgeois, Irish, British, and Danes.  We achieve this while spending, collectively, much more on health care than any of them: about $6,714 a year for every American.  In Japan, by contrast, health-related expenditures amount to about $2,600 per head, and in Portugal to only $2,000.  What’s more, allocating health care by patients’ ability to pay rather than an analysis of the costs and benefits of treatment ensures that the American distribution of health, and life, is as inequitable as one can get in the industrial world.  More than half of Americans who earn less that the average income report not being able to get needed health care due to its cost.  This compares to fewer than 10  percent of the British or the Dutch.
 
Americans are inveigled by a powerful mirage: that markets don’t ration.  In 2007, the Congressional Budget Office issued a report about how the nation might bring spiraling health care costs under control by measuring the cost-effectiveness of medical treatments, as several other countries do.  The report warned that putting a price on life might be politically tricky in the United States.  “Many people find the notion uncomfortable if not objectionable,” noted the CBO, incompatible with “the sentiment that no expense should be spared to extend a patient’s life.”  The invisible hand of the market is as ruthless in denying health care to the needy as the most coldhearted central planner.  Our willingness to acknowledge life’s price does not mean it doesn’t have one.

Excerpted from Eduardo Porter’s The Price Of Everything: Solving The Mystery of Why We Pay What We Do (2011), pages 54-58.

Wednesday, May 15, 2013

It’s been 15 years since Harvard professor Regina Herzlinger coined the phrase “consumer-driven health care” and, in the time sense, everyone from right to left on the political spectrum – from Newt Gingrich to Nancy Pelosi – has been promising us tools for comparison shopping health care in the same way we do for homes, automobiles, and groceries.

What tools have we got so far to compare the cost and quality of medical providers?
One resource for comparing costs of medical services and procedures is FAIR Health’s “Consumer Cost Lookup” website at www.fairhealthconsumer.org


As the above illustrates, part of using this application requires knowing the “CPT code” for a medical service or procedure.  What’s a CPT code?   

CPTs are five-digit codes developed by the American Medical Association as short-hand for long descriptions of services and procedures.  CPT code 99203, for example, is an “Office or other outpatient visit for the evaluation and management of a new patient.”
Ask your doctor which CPT code(s) he or she expects to bill for your service or procedure. 

CPT code 22523, for purposes of the example below, is “Percutaneous vertebral augmentation, including cavity creation (fracture reduction and bone biopsy included when performed) using mechanical device, 1 vertebral body, unilateral or bilateral cannulation (eg, kyphoplasty); thoracic.”

This is a minimally invasive procedure for repairing fractures in spinal vertebrae. 


Consumer Cost Lookup shows the average charge in a community. 
 

Ask your surgeon how much he or she typically charges for your service or procedure, then compare that with FAIR Health data.

When considering surgery, bear in mind that you’ll want to research not just surgeons but facilities (hospitals or ambulatory surgery centers) and anesthesiologists as well.
At present, FAIR Health’s Consumer Cost Lookup offers little information on anesthesiology – and none at all regarding facilities. 

That said, some federal and state agencies offer cost information about hospitals and surgery centers.  The Agency for Health Care Administration (AHCA) in Florida, for example, reproduces facility cost and utilization data at
www.floridahealthfinder.gov/CompareCare/SelectChoice.aspx  
Similarly, the national Center for Medicare & Medicaid Services (CMS) at http://www.cms.gov/Research-Statistics-Data-and-Systems/Statistics-Trends-and-Reports/Medicare-Provider-Charge-Data/index.html