Economists
specialize in pointing out unpleasant trade-offs — a skill that is on full
display in the health care debate.
We
want patients to receive the best care available. We also want consumers to pay
less. And we don’t want to bankrupt the government or private insurers.
Something must give.
The
debate centers on how to make these trade-offs, and who gets to make them. The
stakes are high, and the choices are at times unseemly. No matter how
necessary, putting human suffering into dollars and cents is not attractive
work. It’s no surprise, then, that the conversation is so heated.
What
is a surprise is that amid these complex issues, one policy sidesteps these
trade-offs. A few drugs — such as beta-blockers, statins and glycogen control
medications — have proved very effective at managing hypertension,
heart disease, diabetes and
strokes. Most insurance plans
charge something for them. Why not make drugs like these free? Not for
everyone, but just the groups for whom they are provably effective.
In
traditional economics, such a policy creates waste. The basic principle is
moral hazard: consumers overuse goods that are subsidized. This is why people
fly in business class when they’re on an expense account but in economy when
it’s on their own dime.
In
health care, a doctor or patient might order an extra test casually, just
because it’s free. This is inefficiency at its worst: from money spent on
costly procedures to tests and medicines that provide little medical benefit,
some actions are undertaken only because someone else picks up the check. To
discourage this waste, insurance plans charge co-payments. The logic is simple:
if patients face costs, they will think more carefully about the benefits.
But
people don’t always follow a cost-benefit logic. Consider a patient recovering
from a heart attack. A small cocktail of drugs may cost a trivial amount — say,
$5 — yet it reduces the risk of subsequent heart disease mortality by as much
as 80 percent. That’s a good deal, but as many as 50 percent of people fail to
take these medications regularly.
The
problem is basic human psychology. Heart disease is
silent, with few noticeable symptoms. You feel fine most of the time, so it’s
all too easy to justify skipping the statin.
The
problem here is the exact opposite of moral hazard. People are not overusing
ineffective drugs; they are underusing highly effective ones. This is a
quandary that two colleagues — Katherine Baicker, a professor of health economics at Harvard, and Josh Schwartzstein, a
professor of economics at Dartmouth — and I call “behavioral hazard.”
We've found that
co-payments do not resolve behavioral hazard. They make it worse. They reduce
the use of a drug that is already underused.
A recent experiment by
a team led by Niteesh Choudhry, a professor of medicine at Harvard,
quantifies the problem. The experiment involved nearly 6,000 patients who had
just suffered a heart attack, and were prescribed drugs known to reduce the
chance of another one — statins, beta-blockers, angiotensin-converting-enzyme
inhibitors or angiotensin-receptor blockers. Half had their co-pays for these
drugs waived; the other half paid the usual fee.
As
expected, more people in the zero co-pay group took the drugs, and their health
improved. Those in the zero co-pay group were 31 percent less likely to have a
stroke, 11 percent less likely to have another major “vascular episode” and 16
percent less likely to have a myocardial infarction or unstable angina. None of these benefits came at a net monetary cost. The
insurers did not spend more in total. By some measures, they spent less.
Behavioral
hazard affects all of the drugs listed above. They are all highly effective,
and yet adherence to taking them is a problem. This is a major financial issue.
The New England Healthcare Institute has estimated that solving non-adherence
could save $290 billion a year, or 13 percent of total annual medical spending
in the United States. A number this large is surely open to quibbling, but
divide it by 10 and it is still a large figure.
I’m
not proposing to make all health care free, or arguing for a return to
so-called Cadillac health plans. Moral hazard is all too real for many
treatments, and in some cases, behavioral hazard reinforces it. Just as people
under-respond to inconspicuous symptoms, they can also over-respond to highly
noticeable ones. People may seek too much care for back pain, for example,
resorting to ineffective or possibly even harmful treatments. Behavioral hazard
suggests that we need even larger co-payments for these overused drugs.
My
proposal is targeted: Take drugs that are shown to be of very high benefit to
some people, and make those drugs free for them.
It’s
a simple policy change, and it isn’t meant as a complete solution.
First,
researchers like A. Mark Fendrick, a professor of internal
medicine at the University of Michigan, and Michael Chernew, now a professor of health care
policy at Harvard, argue eloquently for
what they call “value based” health insurance. All
co-pays should depend on measured medical value; high co-pays should be
reserved for drugs and medical services that have little proven value.
Second,
some people will neglect to take their medications even if co-pays are zero.
This proved true even in the Choudhry study.
Fully
solving this problem requires more creativity. GlowCaps, for example, are high-tech tops for pill bottles. They beep and text you if you
forget to take your medication. In another approach, Kevin Volpp,
a professor of medicine and health care management at the University of
Pennsylvania, and his colleagues use lotteries, giving
people a chance to win only if they take their medications.
Finally,
some will suggest that focusing on drug adherence is like closing the barn
door. Why not focus instead on the behaviors — eating unhealthy foods or
shunning exercise — that created the conditions we must now treat with drugs?
Each
of these points has some merit. But they fail the “perfect as the enemy of the
good” test. Sure, we should do more. But meanwhile, why continue to charge the
same co-pay for statins and beta-blockers as we do for Viagra? At the very least,
we need to experiment more with this policy.
“When a Co-Pay Gets in the Way of Health” by
Senhill Mullainathan in The New York
Times on August 11, 2013. Mullainathan
is a professor of economics at Harvard.
No comments:
Post a Comment